Three Cheers for the Subconscious
by
Ross M. Miller
Miller Risk Advisors
www.millerrisk.com
June 21, 2004
My subconscious wrote most of this commentary. It writes most of all of
them. I start thinking about each one a week to ten days before I post
them and begin work on a rough draft somewhere around the time the week's
PGA tournament pops up on basic cable. I then sleep on the commentary and
play with it a little each day until I post it Monday morning. If you
don't like any of these commentaries, blame my subconscious. If they still
have some typos or sentences that don't quite make sense, blame my
subconscious as well—it creates so many of them
that it is hard for me to edit them all out as much as I would like to.
Life for me is, for the most part, easy—I just
glide through it and let my subconscious do all the heavy lifting.
As I was writing the first draft of this commentary, the Dubliners were
just wrapping up their centenary celebration of Bloomsday. I like James
Joyce not because he is recognized as the first writer to place seemingly
uncensored subconscious thoughts on paper, but rather because he's such a
hard act to follow that he has given literary types headaches that
continue to this day. Joyce claimed my father as one of his victims and I
grew up with dog-eared copies of Ulysses and Finnegan's Wake
as well as the various "skeleton keys" for them peering down at
me from the mahogany bookcase that filled the far wall of his study. Freud
and Jung were also up there, but I'll get to them later.
It was not James Joyce, but rather gasoline hoarding, that served as
the initial inspiration for this piece. In "Black
Gold or Bubbling Crude?" I noted that as gasoline prices rise
many drivers tend to fill up their tanks more often even if they are not
consciously aware of it. At some level, they realize that if prices are
climbing rapidly, it costs more to wait than to buy now. This behavior is
not universal—some drivers are strapped for cash
and others try to delay the agony of higher prices—but
it is prevalent enough that it can make a real difference in a market
where supplies are measured in days of consumption.
How can I know what lurks in the subconscious of consumers? Largely
from exposure to experimental economics at a tender age. The
first experiments that I ever designed and ran involved a sequence of
markets where the subjects had to figure out to store a commodity during a
low-demand period for consumption in a high-demand period. The pull of the
price mechanism was so strong that subjects "did the right
thing" from the perspective of economic theory without being
consciously aware that they were doing so. This went against the dominant
theory of human economic decision-making of the time: Herbert Simon's
theory of satisficing. Simon thought people would economize in the making
of complex decisions and so would "satisfice" by applying rules
of thumb that would do an adequate, though not optimal, job of
decision-making. We (my collaborators were Charles Plott and Vernon Smith)
were seeing almost the opposite behavior; experimental subjects were
making the correct, sophisticated choices without any awareness of what
they were doing. (We discovered this by interviewing the subjects after
each experiment.) The feedback of the market mechanism--make the right
decision and you make more money--was all that was necessary to turn our
subjects into optimal hoarders.
That the most complex part of financial and economic decision-making
goes on beneath the surface and is only brought to the surface by the
feedback of the marketplace appears to have been lost on psychologists
going all the way back to the original Tversky-Kahneman experiments. Those
experiments, as well as many that have followed in their footsteps, use
questionnaires that ask subjects "what they would do" (a
conscious decision) rather than observe what they do (which includes
subconscious elements). Taking monetary payoffs out of the picture
entirely removes any punishment for wrong decisions and any reinforcement
for the right ones. (One would think that psychologists, of all people,
would know better.) Recently, both economists, including Vernon Smith, and
psychologists have begun to use neural mapping techniques to see exactly
what is going on in the brain when subjects make their choices.
The fascinating thing about the subconscious element of market
decision-making is that it doesn't stop at the individual level. For most
of the twentieth century, the textbook explanation for how markets could
balance supply and demand was that everyone in the market had
"perfect information" and consciously computed the
market-clearing price and quantity. One voice in the wilderness, F.A.
Hayek's, insisted that perfect information was unnecessary. He saw that
what Carl Jung might call the "collective unconscious of the
market" and what Adam Smith called the "invisible hand"
would bring prices and quantities into equilibrium automatically, without
special information and certainly without the conscious efforts of a
central planner. Thousands of economic experiments, including those that
got Vernon Smith his Nobel Prize, have confirmed that this happens in a
controlled setting and is easily reproduced under a variety of conditions.
To be even-handed, it is also possible to create and reproduce market
bubbles in the laboratory, but this result, which was not recognized by
the Swedish Academy, does not imply that economic decisions should be
handed over to a politburo consisting of the New York Times opinion
columnists, all of whom would have us think that they know what is best
for the world.
Many people, however, would be happy to let Paul Krugman run the
Federal Reserve and Maureen Dowd regulate the manufacture of condoms
because of what appears to be a universal fear of the subconscious, both
individually and collectively. While I am happy to allow my subconscious
to place "Maureen Dowd" and "condom" in the same
sentence, many writers are fearful of what might come spurting out of
theirs. (I didn't forget about Freud.) Similarly, economic processes that
work in mysterious ways and can do quite well without conscious
intervention tend to make people uncomfortable.
Of course, if you really want to get an up-close and personal look at
my subconscious, visit RiggedOnline.com
and read my novel Rigged. In the process of editing it, I have
discovered many things that my subconscious slipped into it and there are
likely several that I haven't discovered yet. For example, the title
itself, "Rigged" contains "ge." Coincidence or a
devious subconscious? Who knows, but I just figured that out a few days
ago.
Next week, it's back to new schemes for making money. "Infinite
Liquidity, Infinite Capital, Infinite Jest" introduces the ultimate
derivative security, which I've probably subconsciously stolen from
someone else. Too bad.
Copyright 2004 by Miller Risk Advisors. Permission
granted to forward by electronic means and to excerpt or broadcast 250
words or less provided a citation is made to www.millerrisk.com.